Introduction

The Japanese public long-term care insurance (LTCI) program was launched in 2000 to curtail the dramatic increase in health care expenditures, as well as to meet the growing demand for long-term care due to the rapid growth of the elderly population. The insurance program was expected to give the elderly, defined as those aged 65 and over, and their family health caregivers, incentives to substitute institutional long-term care in hospitals and nursing homes with less costly community-based formal and informal home care. The program was considered to be extremely important not only to resolve the budget crisis but also to meet the health care needs of the elderly, who prefer to be cared for at home while physically impaired. However, the implemented community-based care program for the elderly is undoubtedly the problem of both the health care system and of society. Socially hospitalized and socially institutionalized issues are still unsolved due to a lack of family and community support.Footnote 1

The central feature of the Japanese government's approach aims to reduce the number of socially hospitalized elderly patients that lead to a rapid increase in health care expenditures in an ageing society. In contrast to the government’s efforts, the local groups put political pressure on the LTCI program and blame it for the inefficiency and insufficiency of long-term care services. A reform of the program for community-based formal home care of the elderly is imperative. There exist various types of long-term care, with different categories. Three main categories exist, which are: nursing home care (institutional long-term care services in nursing home), community-based formal home care (skilled and semi-skilled home care services at home) and informal home care (provided at home by family members). However, within these categories there exist sub-categories, especially regarding community based formal home care, as shown later in Tables 1 and 2.

Table 1 Long-term care and their characteristics
Table 2 Definition of variables and their descriptive statistics

There have been a number of papers showing that the interactions between nursing home care and community-based formal home care depend on the Medicaid benefits,Footnote 2 the quality of nursing home care and the respective public reimbursement program.Footnote 3 (The Appendix summarizes and reviews these results, highlighting the major characteristics of each study.) Other studiesFootnote 4 support the substitution of community-based formal/informal care for nursing home care, while some scholars emphasize the role of the spouse and the children.Footnote 5 On the other hand, Moscovice et al.Footnote 6 and Paulus et al.Footnote 7 underscore a lack of substitution between community-based formal home care and informal home care. Bauer,Footnote 8 Portrait et al.,Footnote 9 Lakdawalla and Schoeni,Footnote 10 Geerlings et al.,Footnote 11 and Puts et al.Footnote 12 ascertained that nursing home entry and community-based formal home care would be affected more by factors related to chronic diseases and functional limitation, rather than by the support network for the elderly.

There have also been quantities of studies that have evaluated long-term care in Japan. SomeFootnote 13 have reported that the prevalence of long-term care depends on health characteristics, including the dependence of activities for daily living; othersFootnote 14 highlighted the role of family caregivers and the burden of taking care of their impaired elderly. Issues concerning hospitals, health care facilities and nursing homes for the elderly have been discussed in many aspects regarding reimbursement programs, that is, fee-for-service system for lengthy hospitalization.Footnote 15 This means over-medication and excessive ordering of laboratory tests are performed for the elderly in the hospitals.Footnote 16 KimuraFootnote 17 suggested a less expensive community-based formal home care, compared to the more expensive hospital care. Furthermore, Sato et al.Footnote 18 affirmed that the interim subsidy for low-income beneficiaries alleviates economic burdens and induces the substitution of home help services. Reimbursement price,Footnote 19 the annual real wage rate,Footnote 20 and price elasticityFootnote 21 are also underlined to facilitate less expensive community-based formal home care over hospital-based care.

Few studies have attempted to identify factors related to the interactions among nursing home care, community-based formal home care, and informal home care in Japan. Regarding the formulation of a policy, which will contain the rising national health care expenditure, the study considers it imperative to clarify these interactions by using the micro-data on the elderly. While acknowledging the previous research on long-term care, the present study pays attention to the decision-making behaviors of the elderly in order to understand determinants of different long-term care services and possible substitution among the services, using the micro data on the Japanese elderly, aged 65 and over. An examination of the socio-economic and demographic characteristics of the elderly, similar to those of the U.S. studies, but drawn from a different set of national characteristics, reveals a new insight into the literature, thereby filling the literature gap. Our findings provide a better understanding of the real needs of the elderly and clarify behavioral decision-making among the elderly who are physically impaired.

The study addresses the concern with three basic questions that are related to long-term health care policy. (1) What are the basic behavioral determinants of the elderly when making choices for nursing home care, community-based formal home care, and informal home care? (2) Do substitutions among the different long-term care programs exist? If so, to what extent do they exist? (3) Does an expansion of community-based formal home care lead to a growth of informal home care by family caregivers, as the national government expects under the current long-term care insurance program? The results of these investigations are important in coping with the problem of rapidly growing public health care expenditures within the ageing society in Japan.

The paper is organized as follows. Japan's long-term care for the elderly is briefly discussed. Then the analytical framework presents a simple model to describe elderly behavioral decision-making among nursing home care with community-based formal/informal home care, and description of data and variables. Next, the empirical results are presented. The final section presents the conclusion, as well as the policy implications.

Japan's long-term care for the elderly

A large number of the Japanese elderly are long-term care inpatients in acute care hospitals. There are two explanations for this. First, the national health insurance system allows for lengthy hospitalization at a minimum cost to the patients; second, there has been a shortage of public institutional long-term health care facilities for the elderly. Consequently, the increasing demand for long-term care due to the rapid growth of the elderly population has forced the Japanese government to develop more nursing homes and community-based formal home care services.

There are four major types of public institutional long-term care services, all of which have different functions and purposes: (1) the long-term care health facility for the elderly (kaigo rhojin-hoken sisetsu in Japanese); (2) the long-term care welfare facility for the elderly (kaigo rhojin-fukushi shisetsu in Japanese); (3) the long-term care for the elderly (keihi-rhojin home); and (4) the community-based formal home services. The long-term care health facility provides institutional care for the elderly during the transition from hospital to home care. Likewise, the long-term care welfare facility also provides institutional care services for the elderly who need constant care but do not live with any informal caregivers at home. Detailed classifications among these public institutional long-term care facilities are shown in Table 1. The national and local governments subsidize the operating costs for these long-term care services. The elderly in the long-term care facilities (i.e., the aforementioned types 1, 2, and 3) are responsible for all daily expenses, and the monthly expenses are determined according to either their annual income or the actual expenses of their daily activities. To meet the needs of the elderly, the community-based formal home care services also offer doctor visits, nurse visits (9,900 nurse stations), home help visits (0.35 million service persons), bathing, meals, laundry services, cleaning, equipment provision, and counseling (in 2004). The public services that were available for community-based formal home care (i.e., the aforementioned type 4) in 2004 were community-based day-service centers (26,000 centers) and short-stay facilities for the elderly (96,000 beds). The day-service centers offer services such as meals, bathing, training and practices of daily activities, guidance, and caregiver classes. The short-stay center for the elderly is a facility for care, not for cure, intended to lessen the burden of family caregivers (e.g., a maximum 7-day stay with a conditional extension). However, in reality due to insufficient provisions of long-term care and community-based formal home care, the elderly are not always able to receive the services at their discretion. The physically impaired elderly often wait a few years at home before being admitted to a long-term care welfare facility.

The long-term care insurance program is under the jurisdiction of the municipal governments. There are two groups of beneficiaries: the elderly aged 65 and over (the first insured); and people aged 40–64 years, suffering from senility (the second insured). The former qualify for formal home care services and long-term care at nursing homes (i.e., the long-term care health facility for the elderly and the long-term care welfare facility for the elderly) and hospitals. The latter can receive these services only when their requirements (e.g., assistance for bathing and clothing with basic activities of daily life) are screened and approved by a long-term care approval board in the municipal government. Although the health care services of the long-term care insurance program generally fall under the jurisdiction of the local municipal or prefectural governments, all of them are authorized and supervised by the national government. Regarding the involvement in financing, the monetary burden of the long-term care insurance program is shared in an amount of 12.5 per cent by the municipal governments; in an amount of 12.5 per cent by the prefectural governments; in an amount of 25 per cent by the national government, and 50 per cent by the insurer. The share by the insurer is contributed by the first insured (18 per cent) and by the second insured (32 per cent), respectively.Footnote 22

Before the long-term care insurance was launched in 2000, long-term care for the elderly was provided as health care services based on the government measures for public health. Following the introduction of long-term insurance focusing on long-term care in 2000, the elderly (the first insured) are required to pay premiums for the insurance to which the people aged 40 and older (the second insured) also contribute, and in turn the benefits are available mainly for the elderly.

Each municipality government makes a long-term care insurance service plan based on identified local needs which have been financed by the public funds through municipal governments in an amount 12.5 per cent, by prefectural governments in an amount of 12.5 per cent, by the national government in an amount of 25 per cent, by the first insured (about 18 per cent), and the second insured (about 32 per cent) since 2000.Footnote 23 In addition to each prefectural plan for a long-term care insurance service support beyond municipal boundaries, each municipal government takes an independent approach to provide well-balanced long-term care by considering the financial burden on the insured and the municipal government. The premium is determined according to the elderly annual income, namely his or her social security retirement benefit.Footnote 24 Furthermore, the premium also depends on the total quantity of care utilization, and the ratio of the elderly to the rest of the population, aged 65 and less, in the municipality. Then, the adjustment is made by the government, and the municipal government receives the subsidy from the national government. The premium is based on the benefit approach, which depends on monthly retirement benefit amounts, and is automatically deducted from the social security benefits. The monthly premium differs slightly from the above-mentioned standard premium according to an elderly retirement benefit level.

Analytical framework

In this section, the empirical framework is discussed, including the theoretical background of health-related issues and the specification of models, followed by an explanation of data characteristics. An assessment of the health characteristics is discussed regarding subjective and objective measures. This empirical study employs objective measures of health characteristics for evaluating elderly behavioral decision-making.

Statistical model

A typical elderly person “i” is assumed to be a utility maximizer and enjoys his or her healthy time. The individual's utility, U i , is assumed to be a function of healthy time L i , informal home care Q i , and a vector of consumption goods Z i , as follows:

Concerning the healthy time, we assume Li is determined by publicly provided professional care services:

where S i,NH stands for nursing home care as a health input; S i,FHC stands for community-based formal home care; and EN i stands for health characteristics of the elderly person, which affect his/her daily living activities.Footnote 25 The relationship between nursing home care and community-based formal home care (∂S i,NH /∂S i,FHC ) depends on whether they are complements or substitutes of each other.

With respect to informal home care, Q i is considered as a joint product of the elderly and family member(s). The production of Q i is assumed to be weakly separable from that of L i in the utility function. Finally, Q i is a function of the caregiver's informal home care services provided to an elderly, S IHC , and a vector of health-promoting consumption goods, H i :

where Y i represents either S IHC or H i , and T denotes time spent caring for the elderly person by him/herself together with a family caregiver. Thus, an increase in T implies a reduction in potential time available for the caregiver's market, as well as other non-market activities.

The budget constraint for the elderly person is expressed in terms of the shadow prices of healthy time, the joint product, and a vector of the prices of consumption goods (for brevity, we omit the subscript “i” to represent an individual elderly in subsequent arguments):

In the above budget constraint, P L is a shadow price of healthy time and depends on the attributes of S NH , S FHC and EN. P Q is also a shadow price of the joint product of informal home care, reflecting attributes of S IHC , and the prices of health promoting consumption goods H. P Z is a vector of the prices of consumption goods Z.

In this model, we assume the elderly person's utility maximization function to be a separable additive function subject to the budget constraint (4):

where the above additive nature implies that the preference is implicitly separable.Footnote 26 From the first-order conditions of maximization, with some modification, we can obtain:

where u′L,S(NH)[=(∂U/∂L)(∂L/∂SNH)]>0, u′Q,S(IHC)[=(∂U/∂Q)(∂Q/∂SIHC)]>0, u′Q,H >0, u′L,S(FHC)>0, and u′L,EN>0.Footnote 27 Equation (6) indicates that the marginal utility of healthy time, with respect to nursing home care, is equal to the ratio of the shadow prices (P L /P Q ), multiplied by the marginal utilities of the joint product with respect to informal home care and with respect to health promoting consumption goods, minus the marginal utility of healthy time with respect to community-based formal home care, minus the marginal utility of healthy time with respect to the elderly person's health characteristics.

In equation (6), an increase in the opportunity costs of informal home care provided by a family caregiver reduces the price ratio P L /P Q and discourages informal care time T. However, a reduction in T increases u′Q,S(IHC), and there is also an input-substitution of H for S IHC (T) in the joint production of Q. Moreover, L(S NH , S FHC ;EN) might be substituted for Q. Therefore, an increase in the opportunity costs will give the elderly person (and the family caregiver) an incentive to substitute nursing home care and community-based formal home care for informal home care. In a similar way, we can also expect a substitution between L and Q (or that between S NH and S FHC ) to respond to a change in the shadow price of the elderly person's healthy time P L . The key implication here is the interdependency among nursing home care, community-based formal home care and informal home care.

Concerning the variables S NH , S FHC and S IHC , in the General Survey on Actual Living Conditions of Elderly People 1990 (hereafter referred to as General Survey) which focuses on behavioral decision-making of nursing home care, community-based formal home care, and informal home care among the elderly for this analysis (see the next section on data and variables), the question of interest for the study is: “When you become bedridden, as a means of long-term care, would you prefer a nursing home or a formal home care facility; or are you indifferent between them?” Hence, the observed values for S NH and S FHC are discrete because an elderly person in the sample prefers either nursing home care or community-based formal home care. The General Survey, however, had no questions related to informal home care to the elderly, that is, the number of informal home care hours per day that family caregivers provide. The sample for the estimation of informal home care hours basically consists of the elderly respondents having bad health conditions. We use the total hours of basic daily activities by the elderly with bad health conditions. The activities are eating, bathing, dressing, toileting, transferring, and bowel and bladder continence, excluding other hours spent on sleeping, associating, resting, leisure, etc. We assume that the activities are assisted by a family caregiver.Footnote 28

The study is concerned with the specifications of our models because of the endogeneity problems of nursing homes, community-based formal home care and informal home care; for this, the study used two ways for testing endogeneity. First, the F-values of the Hausman-Wu test were examined by following HausmanFootnote 29 and Nakamura and Nakamura.Footnote 30 The study applied the Hausman-Wu test for these specifications and accepted the null hypothesis that there is no simultaneity between the variables in question.Footnote 31 Second, the study used the t-test method described in GujaratiFootnote 32 and Wooldridge.Footnote 33 The results also show that there is no endogeneity of the variables. Therefore, a simultaneous-equation approach is not used for the models in this paper.Footnote 34

In order to simplify the analysis, the study used a logit model (LOGIT) for nursing home care S NH and community-based formal home care S FHC , and an ordinary least squares model (OLS) for informal home care S IHC .Footnote 35 In the probability estimation of choosing formal home care services, the questionnaire in the General Survey is, “When you become bedridden, which would you choose among the community-based formal home care services (i.e., community-based day-service and short-stay facility centers, doctor visits, nurse visits, home help visits, bathing, meals, etc.)? Name three at most.” We group the various formal home care services into day&short center, skilled home care and semi-skilled home care, as shown in Table 2. Skilled home care consists of medically oriented community-based formal home care services such as doctor visits and nurse visits. Semi-skilled home care includes non-medical services such as home help visits, bathing, and meals services.Footnote 36 Therefore, the logit model of this study seems less hazardous than a multinomial logit model since the latter must choose an arbitrary combination of various formal home care services.

Accordingly, we separately estimate the following simple models.

and

where NH stands for nursing home care, FHC for community-based formal home care, and IHC for informal home care. AVF and EC represent availability of family assistance, and a vector of economic factors, respectively. EN represents the health characteristics of an elderly individual. SD indicates a vector of socio-demographic factors of the individual: gender, age, community associations, etc. Although many aspects of public nursing homes across the country have been assimilated by the national government, the quality of nursing home care services most likely varies in different places. As no information is available to correct those deficiencies, the study is unable to mitigate the possible bias(es). In addition, the study does not impose supply constraints in the regression analysis, because the fees at public nursing homes and community-based formal home care services are fixed across the country, but vary according to the service recipient's income.

Data and variables

This study uses the General Survey (Khonensha Seikatsu Jittai Sougo Chosa in Japanese) as a natural experiment to investigate behavioral decision-making of nursing home care and community-based formal/informal home care among the elderly, aged 65 and over. The General Survey is a two-stratified random sample of 3,000 elderly, aged 65 and over, staying at home throughout Japan, and was conducted by the Pension Research Center (the Nenkin Sogo Kenkyu Center in Japanese). The survey was a one-time survey sponsored by the Japan Ministry of Health, Labor and Welfare. The data is the latest one we are able to obtain. The number of respondents who returned their forms was 2,529. As some respondents did not provide the necessary information for this analysis, our sample size became 2,501. The definitions of all variables used in this study and their statistics are reported in Table 2.

Another aspect of the retrospective data analysis for behavioral choice is that the data does not include supply side measures – prices and facility locations. This study does not integrate supply constraints, and this may lead to a biased estimation. However, under the national health insurance system, there are few variations of prices for services to the elderly. Each choice of service costs a different amount, and the cost depends on personal finances. Economic factors (wealth, home ownership and income variables) in this study are used as a proxy for the availability of services. A binary variable of urban-rural differentials is also used to represent taste as well as the accessibility of nursing home and community-based formal home care services. Thus, these economic and demographic variables in our model may mitigate our biased estimation due to the lack of supply side measures.

An assessment of the health characteristics of the elderly is often an important issue in the literature. Previous research recommends objective indicators of health status (i.e., ADL (or activities of daily living) and IADL (or instrumental activities of daily living)) because of difficulties in comparing measures of self-evaluated health status among respondents, that is, subjective measures.Footnote 37 Greene et al.Footnote 38 employed three different measurements of health status in their analysis of transition from community to nursing homes: instrumental activities of daily living, cognitive impairment, and self-evaluated health. Nishiwaki et al.Footnote 39 used dependence for activities of daily living. Their results also recommend the use of objective indicators on the health status of the elderly. Using the questionnaire in our data (see Table 2), the study generates the following objective measures of the health status: physical dependence, instrumental dependence, memory, and psychological status (i.e., depressed affect).

Of the other socio-economic and demographic factors studied in this analysis, the study includes economic factors, such as the elderly person's monthly income, wealth, and home ownership. These economic variables reflect not only the monetary value of an elderly person's healthy time but also the capability to pay the monthly charges of the different long-term health care facilities. For the expected effects of the economic variables, since staff intensity and higher skilled staff at nursing homes may represent better quality of services, the elderly with more wealth may prefer a nursing home with better quality, holding the elderly health status and other socio-demographic characteristics constant.Footnote 40 On the other hand, home ownership may reflect a strong psychological and social attachment to the community.Footnote 41 Thus, the expected effect of this variable is negative on the probability of choosing nursing home care. The age and gender variables are expected to reflect health and preference differentials. Variables representing social attitudes among the elderly are also included (i.e., not outgoing, no friends, association, and communication variables).

Empirical results

Table 3a presents the estimates of our logit model of nursing home care, community-based day-service and short-stay facility centers (day&short center), and skilled home care. These variables are defined in Table 2. Table 3b reports the logit estimates of semi-skilled home care and of formal home care, and the ordinary least squares estimates of informal home care. This paper first reviews the major empirical results of each model, and then concentrates its discussion on the interactions among nursing home care, community-based formal home care, and informal home care.

Table 3 Regression results: nursing home care, day&short center and skilled home care
Table 4 Regression results: semi-skilled home care, formal home care and informal home care

Behavioral determinants: nursing home care, day&short center and skilled home care

The first column of Table 3a presents the results of influential factors that affect an elderly person's behavioral choice of nursing home care use when she/he is bedridden. The coefficient of the day&short center in this specification is statistically significant. An elderly person who wants to use a day&short center is less likely to use nursing home care services. The variables of skilled home care services such as doctor and nurse visits are positively associated with nursing home care at different levels of significance. The positive influence of skilled home care services by doctors and nurses implies that an elderly person who wants to use nursing home care services when she/he is bedridden, is influenced by a medical doctor's advice and services at home, and is more likely to be recommended to use nursing home care services. On the other hand, semi-skilled formal home care services, such as home help visits, bathing, and meals services are negatively associated with nursing home care. Interesting results from objective health show that advanced levels of functional limitations of physical and instrumental dependences have significant and positive influences on the use of nursing home care services, while mental and psychological aspects of advanced level of memory dependence and depressed affect have substantial and negative effects on the use of nursing home care services.

The second column of Table 3a shows the coefficients of influential factors on the day&short center. The evidence shows that an elderly person who wants to use nursing home care services is less likely to use community-based day-services and short-stay facility centers. Skilled home care services by doctor and nurse visits and semi-skilled home care services, including home help visits, bathing, and meals, are statistically significant and have positive influences on day&short center services. For skilled home care services in column 3 of Table 3a, nursing home care and day&short center services are negatively associated with skilled home care services, and semi-skilled home care services are positively associated with skilled home care services. Semi-skilled home care services seem to increase the probability of getting skilled home care services. The results of objective health in day&short centers and skilled home care services do not show comprehensible systematic influences on an elderly person's behavioral choice, and an elderly person with instrumental dependence I or II is more likely to get skilled home care services.

Behavioral determinants: semi-skilled home care, formal home care and informal home care

The coefficient of nursing home care in the model of semi-skilled home care services is statistically significant and negative in the first column of Table 3b. An implication of the result is that the negative coefficients of semi-skilled home care services (home help visits, bathing and meals) in the nursing home equation of Table 3a display the substitutive relationship between semi-skilled home care services and nursing home care services. Skilled home care services are likely to reduce the probability of using semi-skilled home care services. Not surprisingly, day&short centers have positive influences on formal home care (defined in Table 2), and the result is congruent with the signs of skilled home care (doctor and nurse visits) and semi-skilled home care (home help visits, bathing and meals) services in the day&short center model in Table 3a. Despite our recommendation in favor of community-based formal home care use instead of nursing home care use for cost-containment purposes, policymakers need to be fully aware that the community-based formal home care services (day&short center, doctor and nurse visits, home help visits, bathing, meals and equipment) neither mitigate nor encourage informal home care use by the elderly, since none of the estimated coefficients are statistically significant in the informal home care equation (OLS) in Table 3b. Based on the results, the study implies that the national government’s attempt to provide more community-based formal care services to reduce expensive institutional care, such as nursing home care services, is an effective cost-containment policy. However, a simple expansion of this service provision will not lead to an increase in informal home care by family caregivers, and neither raises nor reduces the burden of care on family members.

As for the objective health condition in the second column of Table 2, the elderly with higher physical and instrumental dependence tend to choose less formal home care services in the second column of Table 3b, as was hypothesized. On the other hand, the elderly with both high memory impairment and the depression affect used more formal home care services, while the elderly with only the depression affect used informal home care. This evidence highlights, to some extent, the reality of a shortage of public long-term institutions that care for the Japanese elderly with memory and mental health impairments.

Substitutive or complementary relationship and interaction: nursing home care, day&short center and skilled home care

Interesting findings are that nursing home care, day&short center, and skilled home care services interactively influence each other, and are found to be the major determinants of behavioral choice of long-term care services. We also note that physical and instrumental dependences, and memory and depressed affect are important determinants on choices of long-term care services.Footnote 42

First, for the interactions of nursing home care, day&short center, and skilled home care in Table 3a, the study shows that the estimated coefficients of nursing home care as a regressor are statistically significant and negative in both the day&short center (the second column) and skilled home care (the third column) equations. That is, an elderly person who wants to use nursing home care services when she/he is bedridden is less likely to use community-based day-services and short-stay facility centers, and skilled home care services. Second, the estimated coefficients of the day&short center as a regressor in the equations of nursing home care (the first column) and skilled home care (the third column) are also negative and statistically significant. There is a tendency for the elderly to substitute day&short center services for nursing home care and skilled home care services. Therefore, from a cost perspective, an expansion of less costly community-based formal home care programs such as day-service and short-stay facility centers would lead to a reduction in the use of costly nursing homes.

The six formal home care services under skilled and semi-skilled home care in the second column of Table 3a are all positively associated and mostly statistically significant in the day&short center equation. Thus, the elderly who demand these formal home care services tend to use day&short centers at the same time. In other words, the relationship between the six formal home care services and the day&short centers is complementary. This result has an important implication for policy development regarding community-based formal home care services within a locality. The positive effects of both doctor and nurse visits in the day&short center equation in the second column of Table 3a may seem contradictory, since, as noted earlier, the day&short center is negatively related with skilled home care in the third column of Table 3a. It is, however, not necessarily so. Medical doctors and nurses who visit the elderly at home are very likely to encourage them to utilize the day&short centers for rehabilitation. An increase in the use of skilled home care increases both nursing home use and day&short center use. The nursing home care use may decline as a result of the increase in day&short center use. The encouragement given by doctors and nurses are highly recommended and cost-effective. That is, the more frequently the day&short centers are used, the less likely both nursing home and skilled home care will be used. Besides, the less frequent use of skilled home care can further reinforce the reduction of nursing home use (see positive effect of doctor visits on nursing home care). As a consequence, cost-containment effects should take place.

To examine whether informal home care is substitutable for nursing home care and community-based formal home care, this study clarifies the relationships among nursing home care, community-based formal home care, and informal home care. In the first column of Table 3a, the estimated coefficient of informal home care is negative (−0.064) and statistically significant in the nursing home care equation, but not significant in both day&short center and skilled home care equations. It is evident that informal home care can be a substitute for nursing home care, but not for community-based formal home care. That is, the elderly, who are receiving more informal home care, are less willing to use nursing home care when they become bedridden. The marginal effect and estimated elasticity of nursing home care with respect to informal home care (a continuous variable) are −0.013 and −0.043, respectively.Footnote 43 A one-hour increase in the use of informal home care per day lowers the use of nursing home care by 1.3 percentage points. This effect of informal home care will be large on a weekly or monthly basis. In elasticity terms, a 10 per cent increase in informal home care use leads to a 0.43 per cent decrease in nursing home care use. If the average time spent on informal home care use is doubled, the effect of informal home care given by a family member on nursing home care use will be about 4 per cent.

Substitutive or complementary relationship and interaction: semi-skilled home care, formal home care and informal home care

As shown in the second column of Table 3b, since the effect of nursing home care on informal home care is positive (0.202), the substitution between informal home care and nursing home care is not dual, but a one-way direction from the former to the latter. Informal home care is not a significant determinant for community-based day-service and short-stay facility centers (day&short center) in Table 3a, skilled home care in Table 3a, and semi-skilled home care in Table 3b, and vice versa, separately. This seems to be indicative of the strong preference of the Japanese elderly for informal home care provided by family caregivers, regardless of a provision of community-based formal home care services. However, when we group the above formal home care services together with the formal home care equation in the second column of Table 3b, the result is somewhat different: the estimated coefficient of informal home care is 0.072, which is statistically significant. Its marginal effect implies that a 10-h increase in informal care tends to raise the probability of formal home care use by 3 percentage points in the second column of Table 3b. Its elasticity implies that a 10 per cent increase in informal home care hours per day will lead to a 0.18 per cent increase in formal home care use in general.

The Japan Ministry of Health, Labor and Welfare reports that one third of family caregivers feel that they lack the appropriate knowledge requisite for elderly care and that they need guidance and training in day&short centers. The present results, however, indicate that this need probably does not mean that they want to substitute community-based formal home care with informal home care, but might only mean that they want the appropriate guidance and training for their specialization in informal home care. Hence, the national and local governments need to carefully assess what kind of assistance is most necessary, appropriate and desirable for the bedridden elderly who want to remain at home with family caregivers.

Socio-demographic and economic factors

Turning to the availability of family caregivers, considering factors such as the presence of a spouse, family structure, and living arrangement with children, there are some noteworthy results. First, when looking closely at the estimated coefficients of the variable “married” (i.e., married and living with spouse), the effects are statistically significant, and are negative in the semi-skilled home care (the first column) and formal home care (the second column) estimations, but significantly positive in the informal home care (the third column) in Table 3b, while not significant at all in the nursing home care, day&short center and skilled home care models in Table 3a. As the study by IwamotoFootnote 44 showed, it is very clear from these results that a living spouse is commonly the primary caregiver for a frail elderly person. The spouse tends to substitute his/her informal home care mainly for non-medical community-based formal home care services.

By assessing the regression results of the formal home care in the second column of Table 3b, the availability of family members as caregivers is negatively associated with formal home care. The cross-comparison of the estimated coefficients of “married” among the semi-skilled home care, formal home care and informal home care models in Table 3b shows the consistency of the effects: the married status is negatively associated with semi-skilled and formal home care and is positively related with informal home care. The results show that an availability of family resources, namely married status, seems to be a good substitute for lower level non-medical or semi-skilled community-based formal home care services.

The elderly person in a two-or-more-generation family is more willing to use nursing home care (see the positive effect of “family” in the first column of Table 3a) than one in a one-generation family. We would normally expect more available hands in a larger family size. This may not necessarily be the case if the youngest generation consists of dependent children. On the other hand, as we expected, the elderly who do not live together with their children are at a high risk of long term institutional care; this is also implied by the significantly positive coefficient of “No children” in the nursing home equation in Table 3a.

The empirical results of economic and demographic factors are assessed. First, “home owner”, as one of the economic variables, has a strong positive effect on nursing home care (the first column) in Table 3a, but has strong negative effects on formal home care (the second column) and informal home care (the third column) in Table 3b. Our results reject a hypothesis of a strong psychological and social attachment to the community. Second, of the socio-demographic variables, by looking at the estimated coefficients in the informal home care model in Table 3b, we note that the coefficient of gender with a negative sign indicates that the female elderly, who are urban dwellers but are not-outgoing types, strongly prefer informal home care to semi-skilled home care to their male elderly counterparts. In contrast, the male elderly are more likely to use skilled and semi-skilled formal home care than the female elderly.

Discussion and conclusion

Before describing the policy implications of the study, a few clarifications should be made. Although some empirical and theoretical studies have shown a relationship between nursing home care and home care in the framework of long-term care for the elderly, there is little empirical work documenting elderly behavioral choices regarding the interaction among nursing home care, community-based formal home care, and informal care. First, this study uses the General Survey on Actual Living Conditions of the Elderly of 1990 as a natural experiment to analyze the elderly behavioral decision-making of nursing home care and community-based formal/informal home care. Second, the study does not incorporate supply facilities and their prices of various services for elderly care due to data availability. Thus, there is not perfect control for the supply side factors. Third, our assumption of this study is based on perfect information, not including search costs, and on constant average health care costs for the elderly for the transfer from an institutionalized care to formal/informal home care.

Empirical findings of this study have many important policy implications for containing the rapidly growing national health care expenditures of the elderly and long-term health care services under the public long-term insurance plan. What are the determinants of long-term health care services? Is it possible to substitute less costly community-based formal home care for institutional nursing home care? The answer is an affirmative one. The findings show the existence of a two-way substitution between nursing home care and day&short centers (community-based day-service and short-stay facility centers) or semi-skilled home care (community-based non-medical home care service, e.g., home help visit, bathing, meal service, etc), as well as a one-way substitution of informal home care for nursing home care. The results suggest that the Japanese public long-term care insurance for the elderly (LTCI) program should be emphasized to develop the close network of day&short centers, semi-skilled home care services, and informal home care services for efficient resource utilization and cost-effective service delivery. Moreover, the results show that the elderly who have advanced levels of physical impairment rely on the use of nursing home care services, while the elderly with memory dependence and depressed affect use more community-based formal and informal care services. For that reason, the development of the community-based formal home care services for the elderly with physical and functional impairment is fundamental.

One important issue needs to be emphasized in the establishment of a community-based formal home care network under the LTCI program. The elderly have strong preferences toward informal home care in the community. However, they often end up with long-term hospital or institutional care (long-term care welfare facilities or long-term care health facilities) due to the lack of a community-based formal home care network (semi-skilled, skilled home care services, community-based day-service and short-stay facility centers, etc.). Lengthy hospital stays as well as use of the most expensive long-term care programs by the elderly (and with relatively low out-of-pocket expenses under the current national health insurance system) are common occurrences and have been causes of increases in health care expenditures. The purposes of the LTCI are to lessen lengthy hospital stays, to call for efficient health care resource utilization and to mitigate the physical, mental and financial burden of family caregivers. As a consequence, the LTCI program would reduce a rapid increase in national health care spending. Thus, it is especially important to establish an extensive network for long-term care services, namely semi-skilled home care services, community-based day services, short-stay centers, and nursing home care facilities. The LTCI network must also have information about the services and the facility capability for consumers (households and the elderly), which would be provided by the current jurisdictions of the local municipal and prefectural governments. In addition, appropriate guidance and training for the caregivers would be useful to maintain a resource of the efficient use of community-based formal home care services in the local jurisdiction.

The results indicate that there is a complementary relationship between skilled and semi-skilled home care services (doctor visits, nurse visits, home help visits, etc.) and day&short centers in the community-based formal home care network. These findings strongly support and help to facilitate the LTCI program under the local government jurisdiction that has been intended to develop community-based formal/informal home care through appropriate networks in the institutional care facilities. Two remarks have to be made pertaining to the LTCI program for the elderly. This study shows, first, that a provision of community-based formal home care services does not give family caregivers incentives to change the amount of their informal home care at home. Second, elderly who receive more informal home care are less likely to use nursing home care when they become bedridden. As expected, the Japanese elderly strongly prefer informal home care provided by family caregivers at home to institutional long-term care. As the elderly desire informal home care much more, more attention needs to be paid to the provision of appropriate incentives to family informal caregivers. Information of each type of community-based formal home care services (e.g. provision, requirement, service capability, etc.) is needed to facilitate the LTCI program,Footnote 45 and compensation to family caregivers for their opportunity costs and in order to reduce their increased burden could both be viable options to effectively integrate informal home care with community-based formal home care programs under the LTCI program.

Another noteworthy finding is that the informal home care positively influences the probability of using skilled and semi-skilled formal home care services at home instead of in an institutional setting. According to our empirical results, an increase in informal care negatively affects nursing home care use through the community-based formal home care services in two ways. One is a negative direct effect on nursing home care services, caused by increasing semi-skilled home care services (home help visits, bathing, meal service, etc.). The second is a negative indirect effect on nursing home care services. Elderly people who are under informal home care tend to use semi-skilled home care services, which create additional incentives for the elderly with informal home care to use the day&short center. Use of the day&short center is also significantly associated with a lower probability of being in an institutional setting for the elderly. As a result, the development of the community-based formal home care with transferring the elderly from institutional long-term care to less costly community-based formal home care would lead to economic gains.

The aforementioned estimation is made to meet the desire of most of the elderly to live within the community. Does the LTCI program guarantee that choice for the elderly? The answer is partially affirmative. A local government official, as a planner, decides and recommends a package of services within the budgetary constraints, and in accordance with the regulations that meet the needs of the elderly. Differences in the individual characteristics of the elderly (i.e., health conditions, availability of family caregivers, and other socio-economic and demographic factors) certainly require different community-based formal and informal home care services. Thus, the national as well as local governments must carefully screen the elderly to identify differences in their priorities, and to consequently provide the most desirable long-term care services within the community. The means which make the LTCI program successful depend on efficiency, effectiveness and fairness. However, it is still difficult to anticipate enough services for the elderly in the communities. The LTCI program allows for-profit organizations to participate in the home-based service market as service providers. The for-profit organizations may not participate or may not provide services to meet market needs/demand, if the local government reimbursement is too low to cover the costs of the operation. Hence, it is possible and essential that the national and local governments entitle private sector insurers to establish a private insurance market for the long-term care services, especially community-based formal home care services, to fill the gap between supply and demand by emphasizing the benefit approach.

Having the appropriate networks with information about services and also having requirements for community-based formal and informal home care are important in promoting the current long-term insurance program. The success of such health care initiatives largely depends on how carefully the programs of community-based formal and informal home care are designed. This study provides strong evidence of the negative relationships between nursing home care and community-based formal home care. It also shows that informal home care negatively affects nursing home care. Therefore, well-organized and well-developed community-based formal and informal home care programs are viable substitution options for costly institutionalized long-term care in hospitals and in nursing homes. Such a long-term care policy may significantly contain the rapidly growing government health care expenditures.