Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Education as a Positional Good: A Life Satisfaction Approach

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we empirically investigate the direct effects of education on utility. Besides investment aspects of education, the focus is placed on its consumption component and on education positional concerns. We use data from the World Values Survey (WVS) and adopt a life satisfaction approach. First, we find that education shows a significant effect on life satisfaction independent of its effect on income, thus identifying a consumption component of education. Furthermore, given that the contribution of education to individual wellbeing might depend partly on relative position rather than absolute levels, we next study whether education can be considered as a positional good. To this end we analyse the relationship between education and life satisfaction for people in different income groups in which the reference levels of education may differ. Additionally, we control for occupational status since benefits from education could appear via occupational benefits. Our results indicate that the contribution of education to subjective wellbeing is stronger as less people attain a given level of education, thus suggesting that this contribution is partly due to positional concerns.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Holländer (2001) provides an extensive discussion on the validity of the statements of the standard utility theory, characterized by independent utilities, and Duesenberry’s approach, characterized by systematically interdependent utilities.

  2. See Weiss and Fershtman (1998) and Frank (2005) for detailed overviews and discussion on positional concerns in the economic literature.

  3. In this paper we will not tackle this experimental economic literature; nevertheless, readers interested on this topic can refer to the work by Solnick and Hemenway (1998), Alpizar et al. (2005), or Carlsson et al. (2007), among others.

  4. The ‘happiness literature’ bases on individuals’ self-reported data about satisfaction with life, happiness or subjective wellbeing. It is noteworthy that satisfaction with life is a component, in addition to positive and negative affects, of subjective wellbeing (Diener 1984). Although recognizing differences in these constructs, throughout the paper we will use the words happiness, satisfaction and (subjective) wellbeing indistinctly.

  5. For an extensive review of this and other explanations to the ‘Easterlin paradox’, see Clark et al. (2008).

  6. Although in this work we will not focus on social returns, it is worthy to note that the implication of the human capital and the signaling approaches clearly differ regarding social returns since the positional component of education will be associated to negative externalities. Extensive discussion on positional externalities can be found in Frank (2005, 2008).

  7. An extensive discussion on the ideas of ‘decision’ and ‘experienced utility’, and their use in economics, can be found in Kahneman and Thaler (2006).

  8. See Wood and Taylor (1991) for a discussion of different individual goals in the social comparison literature.

  9. A detailed description of the variables used in this study is given in the Appendix.

  10. According to the European Union ‘Directive on Recognition of Professional Qualifications (2005/36/EC)’, liberal professions are defined as “those practised on the basis of relevant professional qualifications in a personal, responsible and professionally independent capacity by those providing intellectual and conceptual services in the interest of the client and the public”. Following this idea, in this study we consider as liberal professionals those working on the basis of a professionally independent work, such as professional lawyers, accountants, teachers, etc.

  11. The WVS asks the individuals to indicate in which income decile their household is placed (see Appendix). Therefore, we do not have data on actual income but subjective data on how the individuals place themselves on the income distribution; for this reason the distribution of the individuals in the low-, middle- and high-income groups is not 30, 40, 30%, respectively, as would logically be the case if we had data on actual income.

  12. Since coefficients in the ordered probit regressions are hard to interpret, which makes comparisons difficult, we also ran several OLS regressions corresponding to each probit model. Not surprising given that there are as many as 10 categories in the dependent variable, the results using OLS are qualitatively identical and quantitatively very similar to those of the ordered probit regressions.

References

  • Akerlof, G., & Kranton, R. (2002). Identity and schooling: some lessons for the economics of education. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(4), 1167–1201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alpizar, F., Carlsson, F., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2005). How much do we care about absolute versus relative income and consumption? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 56, 405–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Argyle, M. (1999). Causes and correlates of happiness. In D. Kahneman, E. Diener, & N. Schwarz (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology (pp. 153–373). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1973). Higher education as a filter. Journal of Public Economics, 2, 193–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1964). Human capital. New York: Columbia University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research. (1993, 3rd ed., Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education. Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

  • Bishop, J. (1994). Schooling, learning and worker productivity. In R. Asplund (Ed.), Human capital creation in an economic perspective. Wurzburg: Physica-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (2004). Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1359–1386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caporale, G., Georgellis, Y., Tsitsianis, N., & Yin, Y. (2009). Income and happiness across Europe: Do reference values matter? Journal of Economic Psychology, 30(1), 42–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, F., Johansson-Stenman, O., & Martinsson, P. (2007). Do you enjoy having more than others? Survey evidence of positional goods. Economica, 74, 586–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., & Oswald, A. (1994). Unhappiness and unemployment. Economic Journal, 14(424), 648–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., & Oswald, A. (1996). Satisfaction and comparison income. Journal of Public Economics, 61, 359–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. & Senik, C. (2009). Who compares to whom? The anatomy of income comparisons in Europe, IZA Discussion Paper No. 4414.

  • Clark, A., Frijters, P., & Shields, M. (2008). Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the Easterlin paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(1), 95–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collins, R. (1979). The credential society: An historical sociology of education and stratification. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diener, E. (1984). Subjective well-being. Psychological Bulletin, 95, 542–575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolan, P., Peasgood, T., & White, M. (2008). Do we really know what makes us happy A review of the economic literature on the factors associated with subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Psychology, 29(1), 94–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duesenberry, J. S. (1949). Income, saving and the theory of consumer behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duncan, G. J. (1976). Earnings functions and nonpecuniary benefits. The Journal of Human Resources, 11(4), 462–483.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human a lot? Some empirical evidence. In P. A. David & M. W. Reder (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth: Essays in honor of Moses Abramovitz. New York: Academic Press.

  • Easterlin, R. (1995). Will raising the incomes of all increase happiness of all? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 27, 35–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (2005). A puzzle for adaptive theory. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 56(4), 513–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckstein, Z., & Wolpin, K. I. (1999). Why youths drop out of high school: The impact of preferences, opportunities, and abilities. Econometrica, 67(6), 133–1295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., & Knell, M. (2004). Choosing the Joneses: Endogenous goals and reference standards. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 106(3), 417–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrante, F. (2009). Education, aspirations and life satisfaction. Kyklos, 62(4), 542–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. (2005). Income and well-being: An empirical analysis of the comparison income effect. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 997–1019.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1985). The demand for unobservable and other non-positional goods. American Economic Review, 75(1), 101–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1989). Frames of reference and the quality of life. American Economic Review, 79(2), 80–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (2005). Positional externalities cause large and preventable welfare losses. American Economic Review, 95(2), 137–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (2008). Should public policy respond to positional externalities? Journal of Public Economics, 92(8–9), 1777–1786.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2002). Happiness & economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartog, J., & Oosterbeek, H. (1998). Health, wealth and happiness: Why pursue a higher education? Economics of Education Review, 17(3), 245–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haveman, R. H., & Wolfe, B. L. (1984). Schooling and economic well-being: The role of nonmarket effects. The Journal of Human Resources, 19(3), 377–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell, J. F. (2003). How’s life? Combining individual and national variables to explain subjective well-being. Economic Modelling, 20(2), 331–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, F. (1976). Social limits to growth. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holländer, H. (2001). On the validity of utility statements: Standard theory versus Duesenberry’s. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 45, 227–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hollis, M. (1982). Education as a positional good. Journal of Philosophy of Education, 16(2), 235–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Thaler, R. H. (2006). Anomalies. Utility maximization and experienced utility. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(1), 221–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kodde, D. A., & Ritzen, J. M. (1984). Integrating consumption and investment motives in a neoclassical model of demand for education. Kyklos, 37(4), 598–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. (1977). Education: Consumption or production? Journal of Political Economy, 85(3), 569–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leigh, J. P. (1983). Direct and indirect effects of education on health. Social Science and Medicine, 17(4), 227–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McBride, M. (2001). Relative-income effects on subjective well-being in the cross-section. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 45, 251–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oosterbeek, H., & van Ophem, H. (2000). Schooling choices: Preferences, discount rates, and rates of return. Empirical Economics, 25(1), 15–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oosterbeek, H., & Webbink, D. (1995). Enrolment in higher education in the Netherlands. De Economist, 143(3), 367–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oreopoulos, P. (2007). Do dropouts drop out too soon? Wealth, health and happiness from compulsory schooling. Journal of Public Economics, 91(11–12), 2213–2229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos, G., & Patrinos, H. A. (2004). Returns to investment in education: A further update. Education Economics, 12(2), 111–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ranson, S. (1993). Markets or democracy for education. British Journal of Educational Studies, 41(4), 333–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schaafsma, J. (1976). The consumption and investment aspects of the demand for education. Journal of Human Resources, 11(2), 233–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, T. W. W. (1960). Capital formation by education. The Journal of Political Economy, LXVIII(6), 571–583.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, T. W. (1963). The economic value of education. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scitovsky, T. (1976). The joyless economy. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solnick, S., & Hemenway, D. (1998). Is more always better?: A survey on positional concerns. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 37, 373–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 355–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1975). The theory of ‘screening’, education, and the distribution of income. American Economic Review, 65(3), 283–300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1898). The theory of the leisure class. Reprinted in The collected work of Torstein Veblen, vol. I (1994). London: Routledge.

  • Weiss, Y., & Fershtman, C. (1998). Social status and economic performance: A survey. European Economic Review, 42, 801–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, J. V., & Taylor, K. L. (1991). Serving self-relevant goals through social comparison. In J. Suls & T. A. Wills (Eds.), Social comparison: Contemporary theory and research. New Jersey: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zavoina, R., & McElvey, W. (1975). A statistical model for the analysis of ordinal level dependent variables. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 4, 103–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

Mª del Mar Salinas-Jiménez and Javier Salinas-Jiménez acknowledge support from the Spanish Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación (ECO2009-13864-C03-01 and ECO2009-13864-C03-02).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mª del Mar Salinas-Jiménez.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 6.

Table 6 Variables definition (from the fourth wave-2005—WVS)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Salinas-Jiménez, M.M., Artés, J. & Salinas-Jiménez, J. Education as a Positional Good: A Life Satisfaction Approach. Soc Indic Res 103, 409–426 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-010-9709-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-010-9709-1

Keywords

Navigation