Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Thoughtfully Reflective Decision Making and the Accumulation of Capital: Bringing Choice Back In

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Quantitative Criminology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we relate a particular type of decision making, thoughtfully reflective decision making (TRDM) in adolescence, to successful and unsuccessful life outcomes in young adulthood. Those who are thoughtfully reflective in their decision making are more likely to consider possible alternative routes to goal attainment, weigh the costs and benefits of those alternatives, and critically revisit the decision once made to examine what went well and what went wrong. We also argue that what mediates the effect of TRDM on later life outcomes is the accumulation of capital. Those who use better decision making practices are more likely to recognize the resources provided by and make the necessary investments to accumulate human, social and cultural capital. These notions are theoretically linked to conceptions of criminal offenders as both rational planners and decision makers and as fully human agents. Using data from the Add Health data set, our hypotheses are largely confirmed. Those who are higher in TRDM as adolescents were more likely to have enrolled in or graduated from college, to be in better physical health, are more involved in civic and community affairs, less likely to commit criminal acts, use illegal drugs and be involved in heavy drinking as adults. TRDM is also positively related to the accumulation of human, social and cultural capital. Finally, a substantial part of the effect of TRDM on young adult outcomes was mediated by capital accumulation. The implications of these findings for future theory and research are discussed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Keren and de Bruin (2003: 348) describe it in the following terms: “The underlying assumption is that, in the long run, good decision processes are more likely to generate good outcomes”.

  2. We would like to be perfectly clear here that by a “quality” decision we are referring to the process by which a decision is made and not the outcome (Edwards 1984). A quality decision is made by considering most of the possible alternatives, by collecting information and making assessments about the probability of each, by revisiting decisions made to learn from successes and failures. For example, a person could have a preference for excitement and risk. Making a competent decision about how to accomplish this goal would entail considering the different ways that one could experience excitement and risk—bungee jumping, riding a motorcycle, investing in the currency market, using drugs, breaking into a store at night. Making a competent or rational decision would consist of thinking about the short and long-term gains and benefits from each line of action and on that basis make a decision. We think that when good procedures are practiced good outcomes are more likely to follow.

  3. There are individual characteristics that make TRDM more or less likely. For example, persons with a high discount rate would on average overweight present consumption relative to delayed consumption and would, therefore, lack the foresight required of better decision making. Youth, who have immature cognitive capacities would, on average, be less likely than those older to have the ability to anticipate long-term consequences (Yurgelun-Todd 2007). However, we would expect to find variation within all ages in persons’ ability to make thoughtful and rational decisions (de Bruin et al. 2007; Fischhoff 2008).

  4. Our understanding of thoughtfully reflective decision making does not deny that some decisions are or should be made by other means, nor it does not deny that emotions may be a part of rational decision making (see Vohs et al. 2007). The relationship between emotions and rational decision making is complex and way beyond the scope of this paper, but we do need to make clear that our notion of thoughtfully reflective decision making is not hostile to the role of emotions nor does it say that emotions are the antonym of rationality. Emotions are strong emotional states that play an important, but currently unappreciated, role in rational decision making. Emotions may facilitate rational decision making by providing motivation and salience for particular types of information, it may, however, also make rationality more complex to understand since what people think they would do in an emotionally “cool” state (say they will use a condom) might not be at all what they really would do in an emotionally “hot” state (throes of passion) (Airely and Loewenstein 2006; Loewenstein 1996; more generally Vohs et al. 2007). The general point we wish to make is that emotions are not hostile to rational thinking and the relationship, both theoretical and empirical, between rational decision making and emotion is one of the most undeveloped but important areas for future work in criminology.

  5. Rescher (2003:9) makes this point most succinctly:

    “Why be rational?”

    “It’s the intelligent thing to do”.

    “But why proceed intelligently?”

    “Come now; surely you jest!”.

  6. This third criterion excluded 12 additional respondents who were either 11, 20, or 21 years old at wave 1 because these respondents were clearly not age-normative for grades 7–12.

  7. One was added to each response so that the distribution began at one rather than zero and all values had a defined natural log.

  8. All respondents in the core sample were at least 18 years old, voting age, on that date.

  9. This criterion was used because at wave 3 many respondents were pursuing a college degree but were not old enough to have graduated. If this variable is recoded to identify only individuals who successfully graduated from college and the sample is restricted to those who were at least 22 years old at wave 3, the results are unchanged.

  10. Although these are very good proxies for TRDM indicators, we would have preferred some more direct measures of respondents’ decision making processes such as whether they made sure they had considered all of the reasonable alternative courses of action and if they thought they generally collected sufficient information about each alternative. This is to admit that we do not think we have a perfect measure of TRDM.

  11. For both of these measures, respondents who were expelled or had dropped out of school were assigned the lowest possible value.

  12. One reviewer remarked that perhaps the outcomes were different enough from one another as to each warrant a unique set of control variables. Because our focus is on the predictive capacity of TRDM for a range of outcomes, we wanted to and did employ an identical set of control variables across models (with the exception of the lagged outcomes). This said, in unreported analyses we followed the reviewer’s suggestion to test the robustness of our findings. For example, when modeling poor health, we included measures of diet and exercise. These supplementary analyses left the ensuing findings unchanged.

  13. Other functional forms were tried for models (1)–(4) and the results were fundamentally the same.

  14. There are no measures of civic and community participation from wave 1—and in any case these are adult rather than child activities. As well, college graduation has no conceptual counterpart to lag at wave 1.

References

  • Ainslie G (2001) Breakdown of will. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Airely D, Loewenstein G (2006) The heat of the moment: the effect of sexual arousal on sexual decision making. J Behav Decis Mak 19:87–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akers R (1998) Social learning and social structure: a general theory of crime and deviance. Northeastern University Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Aschaffenburg K, Maas I (1997) Cultural and educational careers. Am Sociol Rev 62:573–587

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron J (1985) Rationality and intelligence. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baron J (2008) Thinking and deciding, 4th edn. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Beccaria C (1963[1764]) Essay on crimes and punishments.Bobbs-Merrill, Indianapolis

  • Bourdieu P (1977) Outline of a theory of practice. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Brehm J, Rahn W (1997) Individual-level evidence for the causes and consequences of social capital. Am J Pol Sci 41:999–1023

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Byrnes JP (2002) The development of decision-making. J Adolesc Health 31:208–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Byrnes JP, Miller DC, Reynolds M (1999) Learning to make good decisions: a self-regulation perspective. Child Dev 70:1121–1140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camic C (1986) The matter of habit. Am J Sociol 91:1039–1087

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman J (1988) Social capital in the creation of human capital. Am J Sociol 94:S95–S120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman J (1990) Foundations of social theory. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornish DB, Clarke RV (1986) The reasoning criminal: rational choice perspectives on offending. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • De Bruin WB, Parker AM, Fischhoff B (2007) Individual differences in adult decision-making competence. J Pers Soc Psychol 92:938–956

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio P (1982) Cultural capital and school success: the impact of status culture participation on the grades of US high school students. Am Sociol Rev 47:189–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio P, Mohr J (1985) Cultural capital, educational attainment, and marital selection. Am J Sociol 90:1231–1261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards W (1984) What constitutes a “good decision”? Acta Psychol 56:5–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eitle TM, Eitle DJ (2002) Race, cultural capital and the educational effects of participating in sports. Sociol Educ 75:123–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felson M (2002) Crime and everyday life, 3rd edn. Sage, Thousand Oaks

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischhoff B (2008) Assessing adolescent decision-making competence. Dev Rev 28:12–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furstenberg FF, Hughes ME (1995) Social capital and successful development among at-risk youth. J Marriage Fam 57:580–592

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gottfredson DC (2001) Schools and delinquency. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gottfredson MR (2006) The empirical status of control theory in criminology. In: Taking stock: the status of criminological theory. Transaction, New Brunswick, pp 77–100

  • Hagan J, MacMillan R, Wheaton B (1996) New kid in town: Social capital and the life course effects of family migration on children. Am Sociol Rev 61:368–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschi T (1969) Causes of delinquency. University of California Press, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschi T (2004) Self-control and crime. In: Baumeister RF, Vohs KD (eds) Handbook of self-regulation: research, theory and applications. Guilford Press, New York, pp 537–552

    Google Scholar 

  • Homans GC (1964) Bringing men back in. Am Sociol Rev 29:809–818

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D (2003) Maps of bounded rationality: psychology for behavioral economics. Am Econ Rev 93:1449–1475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Slovic P, Tversky A (1982) Judgment under uncertainty: Hueristics and Biases. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Keckes J (1976) A justification of rationality. State University of New York Press, Albany

    Google Scholar 

  • Keren G, de Bruin WB (2003) On the assessment of decision quality: Considerations regarding utility, conflict and accountability. In: Hardman D, Macchi L (eds) Thinking: psychological perspectives on reasoning, judgment and decision making. John Wiley, New York, pp 347–363

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein G (1996) Out of control: visceral influences on behavior. Organ Behav Hum Decis Mak Process 65:272–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCarthy B (2002) New economics of sociological criminology. Annu Rev Sociol 28:417–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Messner SF, Baumer EP, Rosenfeld R (2006) Dimensions of social capital and rates of criminal homicide. Am Sociol Rev 69:882–903

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagin DS (2007) Moving choice to center stage in criminological research and theory: The American society of criminology 2006 Sutherland address. Criminology 45:259–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagin D, Paternoster R (1993) Enduring individual differences and rational choice theories of crime. Law Soc Rev 27:467–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagin D, Paternoster R (1994) Personal capital and social control: the deterrence implications of a theory of individual differences in offending. Criminology 32:581–606

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paternoster R, Pogarsky G (2009) Rational choice, agency, and thoughtfully reflective decision making: the short and long-term consequences of making good choices. J Quant Criminol 25:103–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piquero AR, Bouffard JA (2007) Something old, something new: a preliminary investigation of Hirschi’s redefined self-control. Justice Q 24:1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piquero AR, Tibbetts S (1996) Specifying the direct and indirect effects of low self-control and situational factors in offender decision making: toward a more complete model of rational offending. Justice Q 13:601–631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Portes A (1998) Social capital: its origins and applications in modern sociology. Annu Rev Sociol 24:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam RD (1995) Bowling alone: America’s declining social capital. J Democracy 6:65–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsay JR, Rostain AL (2008) Cognitive behavioral therapy for adult ADHD: an integrative psychosocial and medical approach. Routledge, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawls J (1971) A theory of justice. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rescher N (2003) Sensible decisions: issues of rational decision in personal choice and public policy. Rowman and Littlefield, Lanham

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson RV, Garnier MA (1985) Class reproduction among men and women in France: reproduction theory on its home ground. Am J Sociol 91:250–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenzweig MR, Wolpin KI (1994) Are there increasing returns to the intergenerational production of human capital? Maternal schooling and child intellectual achievement. J Hum Resour 29:670–693

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith MH, Beaulieu LJ, Seraphine A (1995) Social capital, place of residence, and college attendance. Rural Sociol 60:363–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teachman J, Paasch K, Carver K (1997) Social capital and the generation of human capital. Social Forces 75:1343–1359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: improving decisions and health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Vohs KD, Baumesiter RF, Loewenstein G (2007) Do emotions help or hurt decision making: a Hedgefoxian perspective. Russell Sage Foundation, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Yurgelun-Todd D (2007) Emotional and cognitive changes during adolescence. Curr Opin Neurobiol 17:251–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ray Paternoster.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 5

Table 5 Description and coding of variables

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Paternoster, R., Pogarsky, G. & Zimmerman, G. Thoughtfully Reflective Decision Making and the Accumulation of Capital: Bringing Choice Back In. J Quant Criminol 27, 1–26 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10940-010-9095-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10940-010-9095-5

Keywords

Navigation