Skip to main content
Log in

Child Care Choices in Spain

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Family and Economic Issues Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we examined the determinants of child care choices among families with young children in Spain, by means of a conceptual framework that encompassed need, costs, and availability. Based on data from the Spanish Time Use Survey and Household Budget Survey, our study indicated that, regardless of model specification, the age of the child, the mother’s labor force decisions, and the prices of child care services available were the most important factors that mothers considered when they chose a type of child care. Day care center services substituted for babysitters when the price of babysitters rose; and relative and parent care substituted for day care centers when these services became more expensive. We found no different sensitivity to price changes for working and non-working mothers. From a public policy perspective, child care price subsidies were found to have much stronger effects on child care decisions than child allowances or public provision of school slots.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Molina and Montuenga’s (2009) characterization of the different welfare state regime types can be very illuminating in this regard.

  2. See the remarks by Grobe et al. (2008) on the relative importance of child care assistance in the US or Forry’s (2009) analysis of the impact of child care subsidies on the financial resources of American families.

  3. Blau and Hagy (1998) estimated the demand for several quality-related attributes of the primary care arrangement jointly with mode choice, hours of care, expenditure per hour of care, mother’s employment status, and mother’s labor supply.

  4. Actually, fertility decisions may also be considered endogenous (see Hotz et al. 1997). Nonetheless, we considered this issue outside of the scope of this paper and followed the existing tradition of exogeneity of the number of children (Blau and Hagy 1998; Davis and Connelly 2005; Del Bocca et al. 2005).

  5. Most families used only one child care mode. We omitted 15 cases in which we could not decide which child care mode was used longest.

  6. The Classification of Individual Consumption by Purpose Adapted to the Needs of Household Budget Surveys (COICOP-HBS) is an international coding system designed for household budget surveys implemented in many countries (INE 2005).

  7. In a logit model, the magnitude of the effect of a change in a variable cannot be directly represented by the coefficient estimates provided by the calibration (Dunne 1984). One must calculate marginal effects directly. For a logit model, these marginal effects can be obtained by the following formula (Train 2003, p. 62): \( {\frac{{\partial P_{ij} }}{{\partial x_{ij} }}} = {\frac{{\partial V_{ij} }}{{\partial x_{ij} }}}P_{ij} (1 - P_{ij} ) = \beta_{j} P_{ij} (1 - P_{ij} ),\) where \( \beta_{j} \) denotes the corresponding estimated coefficient.

  8. We have used regional data. County level data or data relative to Spanish provinces would be very illuminating.

  9. Within each block, we tested for equality of means of each characteristic between the treated and the control units. This is a necessary condition for the balancing property. The results are not reported but are available upon request from the authors.

  10. Other methods include Dubin and McFadden’s (1984) or Dahl’s (2002).

References

  • Baydar, N., Greek, A., & Gritz, M. R. (1999). Young mothers’ time spent at work and time spent caring for children. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 20(1), 61–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1981). A treatise on the family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. O., & Ichino, A. (2002). Estimation of average treatment effects based on propensity scores. Stata Journal, 2(4), 358–377.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi, S. M. (2000). Maternal employment and time with children: Dramatic change or surprising continuity? Demography, 37(4), 401–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bittman, M., Craig, L., & Folbre, N. (2004). Packaging care: What happens when parents utilize non-parental childcare. In M. Bittman & N. Folbre (Eds.), Family time: The social organization of care (pp. 133–151). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau, D. (2003). An economic perspective on child care policy. Journal of Population and Social Security (Population), 1, 426–445.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau, D., & Hagy, A. (1998). The demand for quality in child care. Journal of Political Economy, 106(1), 104–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, D., & Robbins, P. (1988). Child care costs and family labor supply. Review of Economics and Statistics, 70(3), 374–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borra, C., & Palma, L. (2006). The determinants of child-care choice: An analysis for the city of Seville. Economía, Gestión y Desarrollo, 4, 181–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2005). Microeconometrics. Methods and applications. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Casper, L. M., & Smith, K. E. (2004). Self care: Why do parents leave their children unsupervised? Demography, 41(2), 285–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaplin, D. D., Hofferth, S., & Wissoker, D. (1996). Price, and quality in child care choice. A revision. Journal of Human Resources, 31(3), 703–706.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, R., & Kimmel, J. (2003). Marital status and full-time/part-time work status in child care choices. Applied Economics, 35(7), 761–777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Craig, L. (2007). How employed mothers in Australia find time for both market work and childcare. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 28, 69–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, G. B. (2002). Mobility and the returns to education: Testing a Roy model with multiple markets. Econometrica, 70, 2367–2420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, E. E., & Connelly, R. (2005). The influence of local price and availability on parent’s choice of child care. Population Research and Policy Review, 24, 301–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dehejia, R. H., & Wahba, S. (2002). Propensity score-matching methods for nonexperimental causal studies. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(1), 151–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Boca, D., Locatelli, M., & Vuri, D. (2005). Child care choices by working mothers: The case of Italy. Review of Economics of the Household, 3, 453–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Boca, D., & Vuri, D. (2007). The mismatch between employment and child care in Italy: The impact of rationing. Journal of Population Economics, 20, 805–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubin, J. A., & McFadden, D. L. (1984). An econometric analysis of residential electric appliance holdings and consumption. Econometrica, 52, 345–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, J. P. (1984). Elasticity measures and disaggregate choice models. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 18, 189–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • MEC. (2005). Estadística de las Enseñanzas no universitarias. Resultados Detallados. Curso 2002–2003. Madrid: Ministerio de Educación y Ciencia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forry, N. D. (2009). The impact of child care subsidies on low-income single parents: An examination of child care expenditures and family finances. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 30, 43–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García, I., & Molina, J. A. (1999). Labor supply, child care, and welfare in Spanish households. International Advances in Economic Research, 5(4), 430–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grobe, D., Weber, R. B., & Davis, E. E. (2008). Why do they leave? Child care subsidy use in Oregon. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 29, 110–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J., & McFadden, D. (1984). Specification tests for the multinomial logit model. Econometrica, 52(5), 1219–1240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. (1974). Effects of child-care programs on women’s work effort. Journal of Political Economy, 82(2), 136–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J., Ichimura, H., & Todd, P. (1998). Matching as an econometric evaluation estimator. Review of Economic Studies, 65, 261–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herbst, C. M., & Barnow, B. S. (2008). Close to home: A simultaneous equation model of the relationship between child care accessibility and female labor force participation. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 29, 128–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofferth, S. L., & Chaplin, D. D. (1998). State regulations and child care choice. Population Research and Policy Review, 17, 111–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofferth, S. L., & Wissoker, D. (1992). Price, quality, and income in child care choice. Journal of Human Resources, 27(1), 70–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotz, J., & Kilburn, R. (1992). The demand for child care and child care costs: Should we ignore families with non-working mothers. The Harris school working paper series 92.01). Retrieved October 8, 2007, from The Harris School Website: https://harrisschool.uchicago.edu/About/publications/working-papers/pdf/wp_92_1.pdf.

  • Hotz, J., Klerman, J., & Willis, R. (1997). The economics of fertility in developed countries. In M. R. Rosenzweig & O. Starz (Eds.), Handbook of population & family economics (pp. 275–347). North Holland: Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • INE. (2002/2003). Encuesta de Empleo del Tiempo. Fichero de microdatos. Madrid: Instituto Nacional de Estadistica.

  • INE. (2004). Encuesta de Empleo del Tiempo 2002–2003. Tomo I. Metodología y resultados nacionales. Madrid: Instituto Nacional de Estadistica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joesch, J. M. (1998). Where are the children? Extent and determinants of preschoolers’ child care time. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 19(1), 75–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joesch, J. M., & Hiedemann, B. G. (2002). The demand for non-relative care among families with infants & toddlers: A double-hurdle approach. Journal of Population Economics, 15, 495–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen, A., Liebowitz, A., & Waite, L. (1996). The importance of child care characteristics to choice of care. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 58(3), 759–772.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreyenfeld, M., & Hank, K. (2000). Does availability of child care influence the employment of mothers? Findings from western Germany. Population Research and Policy Review, 19, 317–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, L. F. (1983). Generalized econometric models with selectivity. Econometrica, 51, 507–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long, J. S., & Freese, J. (2001). Regression models for categorical dependent variables using STATA. College Station, TX: Stata Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Molina, J. A., & Montuenga, V. M. (2009). The motherhood wage penalty in Spain. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 30(3), 237–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monna, B., & Gauthier, A. H. (2008). A review of the literature on the social and economic determinants of parental time. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 29, 634–653.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Navarro, V. (2006). El subdesarrollo social de España. Madrid: Anagrama.

    Google Scholar 

  • INE. (2005). Encuesta Continua de Presupuestos Familiares. Ficheros de microdatos. Madrid: Instituto Nacional de Estadistica.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2005). Society at a glance: OECD social indicators 2005. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2007a). Employment outlook 2007. Paris: OECD.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2007b). Social expenditure database (SOCX, www.oecd.org/els/social/expenditure).

  • Powell, L. M. (1997). The impact of child care costs on the labor supply of married mothers: Evidence from Canada. Canadian Journal of Economics, 30(3), 577–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, L. M. (2002). Joint labor supply and childcare choice decisions of married mothers. Journal of Human Resources, 37(1), 106–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ribar, D. C. (1992). Child care and the labor supply of married women. Journal of Human Resources, 27(1), 134–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ribar, D. C. (1995). A structural model of child care and labor supply of married women. Journal of Labor Economics, 13(3), 558–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenbaum, P. R., & Rubin, D. B. (1983). The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects. Biometrica, 70(1), 41–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Train, K. E. (2003). Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrohlich, K. (2006). Labor supply and child care choices in a rationed child care market (IZA Discussion Paper No. 2003). Retrieved October 8, 2007, from Institute for the Study of Labor Website: ftp://repec.iza.org/RePEc/Discussionpaper/dp2053.pdf.

Download references

Acknowledgment

The authors wish to acknowledge the helpful comments of two reviewers and the editor of this journal and the excellent editorial assistance of Julie Barber and Bruce Berry.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cristina Borra.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Statistical Matching

In this section we explain how the statistical matching was performed. Matching involves pairing units, from different datasets, that are similar in terms of their observable characteristics. In this case, the recipient dataset was the Spanish Time Use—TU Survey (INE 2002/2003) and the donor dataset was the Spanish Household Budget—HB Survey (INE 2005), both representative of the Spanish population. These two sets of information share important observable characteristics.

As Dehejia and Wahba (2002) stated, with a small number of characteristics (for example, two binary variables), matching is straightforward (one would group units in four cells). However, when there are many variables, as in the present situation, we need to define a function which measures the similarity between the individuals of the two samples and solves the dimensionality problem. As emphasized by Del Boca et al. (2005), propensity score-matching methods (Rosenbaum and Rubin 1983) provide specific criteria to assign to each individual of the recipient data set a similar individual from the donor dataset. Each pair of individuals created according to this procedure will give origin to an integrated record, with the relevant information from both surveys.

For the present study, two statistical matching processes were performed, one for day care center users and one for babysitter users. We selected households with children under four using each particular type of care. For the babysitter option, 162 were selected from the Time-Use Survey and 224 from the Household Budget Survey. For the day care center option, 521 observations were selected from the Time-Use Survey, and 402 from the Household Budget Survey. As a baseline analysis, we compared the averages for the variables the two surveys had in common. Table 8 presents weighted tabulations on the most relevant variables for both care types in both surveys.

Table 8 Comparison of recipient and donor datasets (Weighted tabulations)

Apparently both surveys were very similar for day care center users. For the babysitting option, within the Household Budget Survey, some regions, like Andalusia or Valencia, were over-represented, as were also very small municipalities. On the other hand, single-parent families were under-represented. Nonetheless, most of the differences between the two surveys were not significant.

Next we needed to match observations from the two surveys for both child care types. As first suggested by Rosenbaum and Rubin (1983), we used the conditional probability of belonging to one of the samples (the so-called propensity score) to reduce the dimensionality of the matching problem previously discussed. This propensity score was computed as p(X i ) = Pr(i ∈ T.U.|X i  = x) (Del Boca et al. 2005). Therefore, rather than match on the regressors, matching was performed on p(X i ).

In order to compute the propensity score, we ran a logit regression of the binary indicator taking value 1 for observations in the Time-Use sample (and 0 for the Household Budget sample) over the set of common household characteristics. We followed the algorithm proposed by Becker and Ichino (2002), which tests if the propensity score satisfies the balancing property (see Cameron and Trivedi 2005). We ended up with five blocks both when assigning babysitting expenditures and day care center expenditures; in each of them the score was balanced across the treated units and controls.Footnote 9

As Del Boca et al. (2005) indicate, since the propensity score is a continuous variable, exact matches will rarely be achieved and a certain distance between individuals belonging to the two samples has to be allowed. Thus, we chose to use kernel-based matching (Heckman et al. 1998), where we associated a kernel-weighted average of the outcome of all donor-dataset units to the unit i of the recipient dataset:

$$ \hat{y}_{i} = {\frac{{\sum\limits_{j \in H.B.} {K(p_{i} - p_{j} )y_{j} } }}{{\sum\limits_{j \in H.B.} {K(p_{i} - p_{j} )} }}} $$
(5)

where \( K\left( u \right) \propto \exp ( - u^{2} /2) \) is Gaussian, p i and p j are the propensity scores of units \( i \in T.U. \), and \( j \in H.B. \), and y j stands for the outcome of individual \( j \in H.B. \) As can be seen, the weight given to donor unit j is in proportion to the closeness between i and j.

After the statistical matching was performed, each individual from the Time-Use Survey using babysitting services (day care center services) was imputed the babysitting (day care) expenditures of a similar individual from the Household Budget Survey.

Finally, we proceeded with an internal evaluation of the statistical matching. We compared the average values of the imputed variable after the matching and the corresponding average in the donor set, that is, the H.B. sample. For the babysitting option, expenditures differed by 14.1% (slightly larger for the fused sample). For the day care option, on the other hand, the difference was 1.7% and not significant at conventional levels of testing.

Appendix 2: Correcting for Selectivity in the Price Equations

Let the price equation for each paid mode j be specified as:

$$ \ln P_{j} = \alpha^{\prime}_{pj} x_{pj} + n_{j} \quad j = 2\left( {\text{babysitter}} \right),\;3\left( {\text{day care center}} \right) $$
(6)

where x pj represents a vector of observed determinants and n j represents unobserved variation. Since we observe prices only if the care option is used, we must account for selection bias in the estimation of Eq. 6. Following Powell (2002) we implemented Lee’s (1983) selectivity bias correction method for multinomial choices.Footnote 10

In the first stage, a reduced form multinomial logit model was estimated from \( \tilde{V}_{n} = \tilde{x}_{{}}^{\prime } \tilde{b}_{n} + e_{n}. \) With these estimates \( \hat{\tilde{b}} \) in hand, we calculated the selectivity correction factors \( \lambda_{j} \) as:

$$ \lambda_{j} = - \sigma_{j} \rho_{j} {\frac{{\phi \left( {J_{j} (\tilde{x}^{\prime}\hat{\tilde{b}})} \right)}}{{\Upphi \left( {J_{j} (\tilde{x}^{\prime}\hat{\tilde{b}})} \right)}}}\quad j = 2,3 $$
(7)

where \( \sigma_{j} \) is the standard deviation of n j, \( \rho_{j} \) is the correlation coefficient between n j and e, the J function is the inverse of the standard normal cumulative density function, and the functions \( \phi \left( \cdot \right) \) and \( \Upphi \left( \cdot \right) \) are the density function and the cumulative function, respectively, of the standard normal.

In the second stage, these expressions \( \lambda_{j} \) were appended to the corresponding Eq. 6 which could now be estimated by (weighted) ordinary least squares. Table 9 presents the results.

Table 9 Child care logarithm of price regressions (Weighted OLS)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Borra, C., Palma, L. Child Care Choices in Spain. J Fam Econ Iss 30, 323–338 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10834-009-9167-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10834-009-9167-6

Keywords

Navigation