Skip to main content

What Failure in Collective Decision-Making Tells Us About Metacognition

Collective Failure and Metacognition

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Cognitive Neuroscience of Metacognition

Abstract

Condorcet [2] proposed that a majority vote drawn from individual, independent and fallible (but not totally uninformed) opinions provides near-perfect accuracy if the number of voters is adequately large. Research in social psychology has since then repeatedly demonstrated that collectives can and do fail more often than expected by Condorcet. Since human collective decisions often follow from exchange of opinions, these failures provide an exquisite opportunity to understand human communication of metacognitive confidence. This question can be addressed by recasting collective decision-making as an information integration problem similar to multisensory (cross-modal) perception. Previous research in systems neuroscience shows that one brain can integrate information from multiple senses nearly optimally. Inverting the question, we ask: under what conditions can two brains integrate information about one sensory modality optimally? We review recent work that has taken this approach and report discoveries about the quantitative limits of collective perceptual decision-making, and the role of the mode of communication and feedback in collective decision-making. We propose that shared metacognitive confidence conveys the strength of an individual’s opinion and its reliability inseparably. We further suggest that a functional role of shared metacognition is to provide substitute signals in situations where outcome is necessary for learning but unavailable or impossible to establish.

This chapter is adapted from: Bahrami B, Olsen K, Bang D, Roepstorff A, Rees G, Frith C (2012) What failure in collective decision-making tells us about metacognition. Phil Trans R Soc B 367:1350–1365

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 189.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    Interestingly, his major case studies, financial bubbles and religious conflicts over Jerusalem, do not show any signs of running out of steam yet.

  2. 2.

    The names chosen for the cricket umpires are inspired by Graham Greene’s (1940) The Power and the Glory (Qodrat o Jalal).

  3. 3.

    The confidence ratio µ i i can be monotonically transformed into P(x > 0), which gives the probability of being correct given perceptual sample x. The decision rule (µQQ + µJJ) is thus equivalent to accepting the decision of the person with the higher probability of being correct (i.e. the higher confidence µ i i ). See the Supplementary Materials to Bahrami et al. [9] for further mathematical details.

  4. 4.

    Thomas Bayes (http://bit.ly/f0uTBk) would perhaps have found the bias for favouring redundant and frequent information only wise and sensible. In the words of Bellman in Lewis Carrol’s brilliant The Hunting of the Snark,

    ‘JUST the place for a Snark!’ the Bellman cried,

    As he landed his crew with care;

    Supporting each man on the top of the tide

    By a finger entwined in his hair.

    ‘Just the place for a Snark! I have said it twice:

    That alone should encourage the crew.

    Just the place for a Snark! I have said it thrice:

    What I tell you three times is true.’

References

  1. Mackay C (1841) The extraordinary and popular delusions and madness of crowds, 4th edn. Wordsworth Editions Limited, Ware

    Google Scholar 

  2. Condorcet M (1785) Essai sur l’application de l’analyse á la probabilité des décisions rendues á la pluralité des voix. de l’Impr. royale, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  3. Galton F (1907) Vox populi. Nature 1949(75):450–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Kerr NL, Tindale RS (2004) Group performance and decision making. Annu Rev Psychol 55:623–655

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  5. Lorenz J, Rauhut H, Schweitzer F, Helbing D (2011) How social influence can undermine the wisdom of crowd effect. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 108(22):9020–9025

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  6. Alais D, Burr D (2004) The ventriloquist effect results from near-optimal bimodal integration. Curr Biol 14(3):257–262

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  7. Deneve S, Latham PE, Pouget A (2001) Efficient computation and cue integration with noisy population codes. Nat Neurosci 4(8):826–831

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  8. Ernst MO, Banks MS (2002) Humans integrate visual and haptic information in a statistically optimal fashion. Nature 415(6870):429–433

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  9. Bahrami B, Olsen K, Latham PE, Roepstorff A, Rees G, Frith CD (2010) Optimally interacting minds. Science 329(5995):1081–1085

    Article  CAS  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  10. Sorkin RD, Hays CJ, West R (2001) Signal-detection analysis of group decision making. Psychol Rev 108(1):183–203

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  11. Ma WJ, Beck JM, Latham PE, Pouget A (2006) Bayesian inference with probabilistic population codes. Nat Neurosci 9(11):1432–1438

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  12. Keysar B (2007) Communication and miscommunication: The role of egocentric processes. Intercultral Pragmatics 4(1):71–84

    Google Scholar 

  13. Gilovich T, Savitsky K, Medvec VH (1998) The illusion of transparency: Biased assessments of others’ ability to read one’s emotional states. J Pers Soc Psychol 75(2):332–346

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  14. Keysar B, Lin S, Barr DJ (2003) Limits on theory of mind use in adults. Cognition 89(1):25–41

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  15. Corallo G, Sackur J, Dehaene S, Sigman M (2008) Limits on introspection: distorted subjective time during the dual-task bottleneck. Psychol Sci 19(11):1110–1117

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  16. Ericsson KA, Simon HA (1980) Verbal reports as data. Psychol Rev 87(3):215–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Sandberg K, Timmermans B, Overgaard M, Cleeremans A (2010 ) Measuring consciousness: is one measure better than the other? Conscious Cogn 19(4):1069–1078

    Google Scholar 

  18. Latane B, Williams K, Harkins S (1979) Many hands make light the work—causes and consequences of social loafing. J Pers Soc Psychol 37(6):822–832

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Karau SJ, Williams KD (1993) Social loafing—a metaanalytic review and theoretical integration. J Pers Soc Psychol 65(4):681–706

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Olsen K, Christensen P, Bang D, Roepstorff A, Rees G, Frith C, Bahrami B (In preperation) Interaction accelerates the rate of visual perceptual learning in humans

    Google Scholar 

  21. Zajonc RB (1965) Social facilitation. Science 16(149):269–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Williams K, Harkins S, Latane B (1981) Identifiability as a deterrent to social loafing: two cheering experiments. J Pers Soc Psychol 40(2):303–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Turner ME, Pratkanis AR (1998) Twenty-five years of groupthink theory and research: Lessons from the evaluation of a theory. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 73(2–3):105–115

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  24. Raafat RM, Chater N, Frith C (2009) Herding in humans. Trends Cogn Sci 13(10):420–428

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  25. Hastie R, Kameda T (2005) The robust beauty of majority rules in group decisions. Psychol Rev 112(2):494–508

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  26. Stasser G, Titus W (1985) Pooling of unshared information in group decision-making: biased information sampling during discussion. J Pers Soc Psychol 48(6):1467–1478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Stasser G, Titus W (1987) Effects of information load and percentage of shared information on the dissemination of unshared information during group discussion. J Pers Soc Psychol 53(1):81–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Stasser G, Titus W (2003) Hidden profiles: a brief history. Psychol Inq 14(3–4):304–313

    Google Scholar 

  29. Fusaroli R, Bahrami B, P, Olsen K, Roepstorff A, Frith C, et al. (2011) Coming to terms: an experimental quantification of the coordinative benefits of linguistic interaction. Under review 2011

    Google Scholar 

  30. Bahrami B, Olsen K, Bang D, Roepstorff A, Rees G, Frith C (2011) Together, slowly but surely: the role of social interaction and feedback on the build-up of benefit in collective decision-making. J Exp Psychol Human Percept Perform 38:3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Burge J, Girshick AR, Banks MS (2010) Visual-haptic adaptation is determined by relative reliability. J Neurosci 30(22):7714–7721

    Article  CAS  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  32. Behrens TE, Hunt LT, Woolrich MW, Rushworth MF (2008) Associative learning of social value. Nature 456(7219):245–249

    Article  CAS  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  33. Behrens TE, Hunt LT, Rushworth MF (2009) The computation of social behavior. Science 324(5931):1160–1164

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  34. Hampton AN, Bossaerts P, O’Doherty JP (2008) Neural correlates of mentalizing-related computations during strategic interactions in humans. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 105(18):6741–6746

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  35. Austen-Smith D, Banks J (1996) Information aggregation, rationality, and the condorcet jury theorem. Am Political Sci Rev 90(1):34–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Blackwell D, Girschick MA (1954) Theory of games and statistical decisions. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  37. Maloney LT (2002) Statistical decison theory and biological vision. In: Heyer D, Mausfeld R (eds) Perception and physical world. Wiley, New York, pp 145–189

    Google Scholar 

  38. Pierce CS, Jastrow J (1884) On small differences in sensation. Mem Natl Acad Sci 3:75–83

    Google Scholar 

  39. Wald A (1947) Sequential analysis. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  40. Gold JI, Shadlen MN (2007) The neural basis of decision making. Annu Rev Neurosci 30:535–574

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  41. Ratcliff R (1978) Theory of memory retrieval. Psychol Rev 85(2):59–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Vickers D (1979) Decision processes in visual perception. Academic, New York

    Google Scholar 

  43. Heath RA (1984) Random-walk and accumulator models of psychophysical discrimination: a critical evaluation. Perception 13(1):57–65

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  44. Kepecs A, Uchida N, Zariwala HA, Mainen ZF (2008) Neural correlates, computation and behavioural impact of decision confidence. Nature 455(7210):227–231

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  45. Kiani R, Shadlen MN (2009) Representation of confidence associated with a decision by neurons in the parietal cortex. Science 324(5928):759–764

    Article  CAS  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  46. Pleskac TJ, Busemeyer JR (2010) Two-stage dynamic signal detection: a theory of choice, decision time, and confidence. Psychol Rev 117(3):864–901

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  47. Glimcher PW, Rustichini A (2004) Neuroeconomics: the consilience of brain and decision. Science 306(5695):447–452

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  48. Hsu M, Bhatt M, Adolphs R, Tranel D, Camerer CF (2005) Neural systems responding to degrees of uncertainty in human decision-making. Science 310(5754):1680–1683

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  49. Huettel SA, Stowe CJ, Gordon EM, Warner BT, Platt ML (2006) Neural signatures of economic preferences for risk and ambiguity. Neuron 49(5):765–775

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  50. Platt ML, Huettel SA (2008) Risky business: the neuroeconomics of decision making under uncertainty. Nat Neurosci 11(4):398–403

    Article  CAS  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  51. Fleming SM, Dolan RJ (2010) Effects of loss aversion on post-decision wagering: implications for measures of awareness. Conscious Cogn 19(1):352–363

    Article  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  52. Ernst MO (2010) Behavior. Decisions made better. Science 329(5995):1022–1023

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  53. Fisher RA (1921) On the probable error of a coefficient of correlation deduced from a small sample. Metron 1(4):3–32

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This work was supported by a British Academy postdoctoral fellowship (BB), European Research Council (NeuroCoDec, grant number 309865), the Calleva Research Centre for Evolution and Human Sciences (DB), the Danish National Research Foundation and the Danish Research Council for Culture and Communication (BB, KO, AR, CF) and by the Wellcome Trust (GR). Support from the MINDLab UNIK initiative at Aarhus University was funded by the Danish Ministry of Science, Technology and Innovation.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dan Bang .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bang, D. et al. (2014). What Failure in Collective Decision-Making Tells Us About Metacognition. In: Fleming, S., Frith, C. (eds) The Cognitive Neuroscience of Metacognition. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-45190-4_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics